Home - Index -
News - Krisen 1992 - EMU - Economics - Cataclysm -
Wall Street Bubbles
US Dollar - Finanskrisen - Houseprices
Stabiliseringspolitik
Keynes’s General Theory at 80
First, Keynes invented macroeconomics – the theory of output as a whole.
Keynes’s second major legacy is the notion that governments can and should prevent depressions.
Milton Friedman reasserted the pre-Keynesian view of how market economies work.
Inflation, Friedman said, resulted from attempts by Keynesian governments to force down unemployment below its “natural” rate.
Robert Skidelsky, Project Syndicate 23 Febr 2016
For 30 years or so Keynesianism ruled
The new assault was led by Milton Friedman and followed up by a galaxy of clever young disciples
Adaptive Expectations, Rational Expectations, Real Business Cycle Theory, Efficient Financial Market Theory – they all poured off the Chicago assembly line, their inventors awarded Nobel Prizes
Then along came the almost Great Depression of today
Robert Skidelsky, Financial Times June 9 2009
John Maynard Keynes and Milton Friedman were the most influential economists of the 20th century.
Their differences were, indeed, profound. But so was what they shared. More interesting, neither won and neither lost:
today’s policy orthodoxies are a synthesis of their two approaches.
Martin Wolf, Financial Times, November 22 2006
The theory that so influences the European policymakers is now the dominant one, at least in the academic world. It has been given various names. Let us call it the new classical theory. It is intriguing that a theory developed by American economists is disregarded by the US authorities but is taken very seriously in Europe.
It is equally puzzling that Keynesianism, which is utterly discredited in the academic world, has continued to guide the actions of the US authorities in the past 10 years, and even seems to be working.
Paul de Grauwe, Financial Times 17/8 2005
John Maynard Keynes:
Fighting for Britain, 1937-1946
by Robert Skidelsky
In the spring of 2005 a panel of “conservative scholars and policy leaders” was asked to identify the most dangerous books of the 19th and 20th centuries. You can get a sense of the panel’s leanings by the fact that both Charles Darwin and Betty Friedan ranked high on the list. But The General Theory of Employment, Interest, and Money did very well, too. In fact, John Maynard Keynes beat out V.I. Lenin and Frantz Fanon. Keynes, who declared in the book’s oft-quoted conclusion that “soon or late, it is ideas, not vested interests, which are dangerous for good or evil,” [384] would probably have been pleased.
But Keynes was no socialist – he came to save capitalism, not to bury it.
Keynes wrote during a time of mass unemployment, of waste and suffering on an incredible scale. A reasonable man might well have concluded that capitalism had failed, and that only huge institutional changes – perhaps the nationalization of the means of production – could restore economic sanity. Many reasonable people did, in fact, reach that conclusion: large numbers of British and American intellectuals who had no particular antipathy toward markets and private property became socialists during the depression
Introduction by Paul Krugman to The General Theory of Employment, Interest, and Money, by John Maynard Keynes
The Unofficial Paul Krugman Archive
Friends, Romans, Countrymen, I come to bury Caesar, not to praise him.
Keynes' 1936, The General Theory of Employment, Interest and Money,
is available free online
With the General Theory, as it became known, Keynes sought to develop an theory that could explain the determination of aggregate output - and as a consequence, employment. He posited that the determining factor to be aggregate demand.
Among the revolutionary concepts initiated by Keynes was the concept of a demand-determined equilibrium wherein unemployment is possible, the ineffectiveness of price flexibility to cure unemployment, a unique theory of money based on 'liquidity preference', the introduction of radical uncertainty and expectations, the marginal efficiency of investment schedule breaking Say's Law (and thus reversing the savings-investment causation), the possibility of using government fiscal and monetary policy to help eliminate recessions and control economic booms.
Indeed, with this book, he almost single-handedly constructed the fundamental relationships and ideas behind what became known as 'macroeconomics'."
The IS-LM framework, invented by Sir John Hicks in 1937 as an interpretation of Keynes's “General Theory”
casts useful light on why bond yields are so low.
The Economist 11/8 2005
In 2013 economists at the IMF rendered their verdict on these austerity programmes:
they had done far more economic damage than had been initially predicted, including by the fund itself.
What had the IMF got wrong when it made its earlier, more sanguine forecasts?
It had dramatically underestimated the fiscal multiplier.
The Economist print 13 August 2016
Highly Recommended
Krugman essay
How Economics Survived the Economic Crisis
Unlike the Great Depression of the 1930s, which produced Keynesian economics, and the stagflation of the 1970s, which gave rise to Milton Friedman's monetarism, the Great Recession has elicited no such response from the economics profession. Why?
Robert Skidelsky, Project Syndicate, 18 January 2018
An elegant essay by the Nobel laureate economist Paul Krugman
His answer to Queen Elizabeth II’s now-famous question: “Why did no one see it coming?” Krugman’s cheerful response is that the New Keynesians were looking the other way. Theirs was a failure not of theory, but of “data collection.” They had “overlooked” crucial institutional changes in the financial system. While this was regrettable, it raised no “deep conceptual issue” – that is, it didn’t demand that they reconsider their theory.
In my view, New Keynesian economists turned a blind eye to instabilities building up in the banking system, because their models told them that financial institutions could accurately price risk. So there was a “deep conceptual issue” involved in New Keynesian analysis: its failure to explain how banks might come to “underprice risk worldwide,” as Alan Greenspan put it.
The return of Keynesianism
Martin Sandbu's Free Lunch, FT 24 October 2016
A speech given by Federal Reserve chair Janet Yellen 10 days ago has received a lot of attention in the economic community
and deserves an even broader hearing.
Its modest focus — it is titled “Macroeconomic research after the crisis” — is deceptive.
Beyond useful research recommendations, Yellen’s words carry more profound implications,
including an admission of the extent to which central bankers are navigating in the dark,
and a return to much more aggressive policies for demand management than modern macroeconomic theory had until recently admitted.
DSGE macroeconomics does not really allow for the large-scale financial panic we saw in 2008,
nor for some of the main contending explanations for the slow recovery and a level of economic activity that remains far below the pre-crisis trend.
Martin Sandbu, FT 19 January 2018
Jag tycker det är skriande uppenbart att räntan världen över är för låg och att en större del av stimulanserna borde ske via finanspolitiken.
Men väljarna och därmed deras medlöpande politiker är rädda för budgetunderskott och vill hellre att villaägarna skall låna än att staten skall göra det.
Rolf Englund blog 5 december 2009
We are all Keynesians now, so let's get fiscal
Monetary policy is close to the limits.
Ambrose Evans-Pritchard 4 August 2016
As a biographer and aficionado of John Maynard Keynes, I am sometimes asked:
“What would Keynes think about negative interest rates?”
Robert Skidelsky, Project Syndicate 24 May 2016
David Glasner: “What’s Wrong with Monetarism?”
Friedman soft in his criticism of Keynesian doctrines
Brad DeLong 27 April 2016
Friedman famously held the Fed responsible for the depth and duration of what he called the Great Contraction…
in sharp contrast to hard-core laissez-faire opponents of Fed policy, who regarded even the mild and largely ineffectual steps taken by the Fed…
as illegitimate interventionism to obstruct the salutary liquidation of bad investments, thereby postponing the necessary reallocation of real resources to more valuable uses…
Friedman has always been regarded with suspicion by laissez-faire dogmatists who correctly judged him to be soft in his criticism of Keynesian doctrines….
Friedman had Keynesian inclinations which, depending on his audience, he sometimes emphasized, and sometimes suppressed
The contemporary central bank based mutation of the old Keynesian and Friedmanite fallacies
is rooted in this debt-centric economics but is far more dangerous.
Owing to his anti-gold standard worldview, Friedman failed to realize that fiat money was nothing more than debt,
but at least he swore an oath of restraint in the form of a fixed rule (such as 3% per annum) for the growth of credit money.
David Stockman, 16 April 2016
We use the term “Keynesian” loosely to stand for economic interventionists of all schools.
The followers of JM Keynes and Milton Friedman alike fit that category.
So do some of the more rabid supply siders who claim the power to stimulate ultra-high economic growth with the tools of tax policy alone.
The common denominator is economic statism.
Resurgent Keynesianism
IMF a worry over insufficient aggregate demand
Martin Sandbu, FT Free Lunch 14 April 2016
For several years now the small coterie of Keynesian academics and apparatchiks
who have seized nearly absolute financial power through the Fed’s printing presses
have justified the lunacy of unending ZIRP and massive QE on the grounds that there is too little inflation.
David Stockman, February 20, 2016
Hayek Versus Keynes
During World War Two, John Maynard Keynes and Friedrich Hayek spent all night together, alone, on the roof of the chapel of King’s College, Cambridge.
“It was, perhaps, the most unusual episode in the long running duel between the two giants of twentieth century economic thought.
John Mauldin, 3 September 2015
John Maynard Keynes Is the Economist the World Needs Now
Politicians ignored Keynes in 1937. Doing so again could tank the economy
Peter Coy, Businessweek's economics editor, October 30, 2014
UK
IMF and its Keynesian fellow-travellers were convinced that his squeeze on public spending meant that the recovery would take years to materialise.
We now know that the Chancellor was right and the IMF spectacularly wrong.
Allister Heath, Telegraph 24 July 2014
None of this is to downplay the UK’s remaining problems. GDP is at a new high but national income per person remains lower than it was: the population has grown, but productivity has fallen; Mr Osborne should have pushed through more supply-side reforms to try to solve this. The average worker therefore remains poorer than before the crisis.
But for all the problems, the real story is that the pessimists were wrong and Britain is booming again – and for that we should all be grateful.
I’ll eat my hat. The St Louis Federal Reserve – the last bastion of monetary orthodoxy in the Fed family –
has just published a paper that basically deems quantitative easing to be useless.
John Maynard Keynes was right all along.
The working paper by Yi Wen and Jing Wu cites China as the world’s resounding success story post-Lehman
Ambrose Evans-Pritchard, March 28th, 2014
While the West and other Brics have deployed the wrong instruments, forgotten the lessons of the 1930s, and failed to recover fully from the slump. It could have been written by Paul Krugman (well, almost).
It makes the point – often forgotten in the West – that China suffered a 45pc collapse in exports when the storm hit, “one of the largest trade collapses in world history since the Great Depression.”
a paper that basically deems quantitative easing to be useless
- Jag tycker det är skriande uppenbart att räntan världen över är för låg
och att en större del av stimulanserna borde ske via finanspolitiken, skrev jag i december 2009.
Keynes, Krugman, Secular Stagnation and The Death of the Rentiers
Izabella Kaminska, FT Alphaville, 23 January 2014
Paul Krugman's point refers to John Maynard Keynes’s famous observation that one day the global economy would rid itself of the plague of economic value-sucking rentiers by arriving at a post-scarcity moment. At such a time an abundance of capital would make economic rent an impossibility.
Rates would naturally fall to zero to reflect the excess of capital, and rentiers would have to die.
Today we’re calling that idea “secular stagnation”. Which of course sounds more impressive than plain old “abundance” and new enough to be able to distance itself from Marxist economics.
One need only look at the trend for the 10-year yield to get the picture:
Based on that analysis, the surest sign that our society is on the verge of exactly such a secular stagnation story is the increasing frequency and severity of bubbles today. But ...
The Euthanasia of the Rentier
Paul Krugman, NYT 22 January 2014
A commenter quotes John Maynard Keynes:
The outstanding faults of the economic society in which we live are its failure to provide for full employment and its arbitrary and inequitable distribution of wealth and incomes.
It is, of course, a perfect quote for our times, too. It comes from the last chapter of the General Theory — a chapter that definitely bears rereading in the light of current debates.
For what Keynes describes in this chapter is, pretty much, a condition of secular stagnation — of persistently low returns on investment, in which there is a chronic oversupply of saving. He believed, in 1936, that this would be the state of affairs in the decades ahead, and was of course wrong in that belief.
But he wasn’t wrong about the possibility of such a state of affairs, and since Larry Summers came out as a secular stagnationist, the view that we may well be there now has gone mainstream.
At present the world’s high propensity to save is not matched by a desire to invest.
High-income economies have had ultra-cheap money for more than five years. Japan has lived with it for almost 20.
The highest interest rate charged by any of the four most important central banks in the high-income economies is 0.5 per cent at the Bank of England.
Martin Wolf, FT May 6, 2014
It's hard to think of a British man born in the 1880s whose name you hear more often, in current debates, than John Maynard Keynes.
I've made a TV series, with help from the Open University, about three economic thinkers from the past who have something interesting to tell us about the financial crisis and how to get past it:
Friedrich Hayek, Karl Marx and, tonight, Keynes.
Stephanie Flanders, BBC Economics editor, 17 September 2012
You might think it an odd trio for a series. Even for BBC Two.
If you've heard Hayek's name, it will have been as Keynes' arch enemy - the "Austrian" economist who wrote the Road to Serfdom and believed that markets should be as free as humanly possible.
And Marx - well, wasn't he some some kind of Communist?
But what all three had in common was that they understood both the genius of capitalism, and its inherent instability.
Har Borg knäckt den keynesianska koden?
Man håller igen när det går trögt och gasar på när hjulen rullar.
Det är inte ortodox konjunkturpolitik, om man så säger.
SvD-ledare 25 augusti 2012
The macroeconomics of John Maynard Keynes continue to dominate the global economic policy debate to this very day.
But many have forgotten that the great intellectual was also one of the most active investors of his era.
Gavyn Davies, Financial Times, August 22, 2012
Man behöver inte tro på Keynes teorier från 1930-talet för att se både
den politiska och ekonomiska faran i en finanspolitik som spär på nedgången.
Det långsiktigt nödvändiga – att sanera skuldsatta ekonomier – är inte en klok strategi i ett akut läge.
Peter Wolodarski, DN 13 maj 2012
Bond yields have been extraordinarily low in the developed world in recent times because the economies have been stuck in, or very near, a liquidity trap.
Longer term government interest rates have remained positive, but at 1.9 per cent they were very close to the territory which Keynes warned about,
in which the future yield on the bonds did not compensate holders for the risk of capital loss if economic circumstances changed.
Gavyn Davies, FT, 18 March 2012
The truth, although nobody on the right will ever admit it, is that
Friedman was basically a Keynesian — or, if you like, a Hicksian.
Paul Krugman, NYT blog 14 March 2012
Economists And Post-Crisis Policy (Also Ireland)
Henry Farrell and John Quiggin have posted their fascinating paper on the rise and
temporary, I think) fall of Keynesian economics in the aftermath of the financial crisis
Paul Krugman, March 11, 2012
Han är bildad, Ambrose; Grekland, Tyskland och the London Debt Agreement of 1953
Rolf Englund blog 13/2 2012
Keynes
Finding the human causes of this financial crisis can set us on the road to recovery
The starting point is to recognise that this proto-depression is not natural or inevitable. It is not the result of destruction through earthquake, or famine.
It results from human actions and inactions.
Confronting the painful reality of depression conditions in the 1930s, he explained how this happened, why it might persist and what needed to be done to overcome it.
Roger Bootle, Daily Telegraph 9 Oct 2011
The post-crisis European Union offers insight into a contentious economic question:
How fast do wages fall in the face of high unemployment?
WSJ 19 Sept 2011
The question is far from academic. Millions of Europeans who lost their jobs in countries hard-hit by the crisis won’t see their prospects improve
until companies believe labor is cheap enough to start hiring again.
It’s tempting to argue that the economic failures of recent years prove that economists don’t have the answers.
But the truth is actually worse: in reality, standard economics offered good answers,
but political leaders — and all too many economists — chose to forget or ignore what they should have known.
Paul Krugman, New York Times 6 January 2013
The story, at this point, is fairly straightforward. The financial crisis led, through several channels, to a sharp fall in private spending: residential investment plunged as the housing bubble burst; consumers began saving more as the illusory wealth created by the bubble vanished, while the mortgage debt remained. And this fall in private spending led, inevitably, to a global recession.
For an economy is not like a household. A family can decide to spend less and try to earn more. But in the economy as a whole, spending and earning go together: my spending is your income; your spending is my income. If everyone tries to slash spending at the same time, incomes will fall — and unemployment will soar.
But it all went wrong in 2010. The crisis in Greece was taken, wrongly, as a sign that all governments had better slash spending and deficits right away.
Austerity became the order of the day, and supposed experts who should have known better cheered the process on, while the warnings of some (but not enough) economists that austerity would derail recovery were ignored.
For example, the president of the European Central Bank confidently asserted that “the idea that austerity measures could trigger stagnation is incorrect.”
I really wonder about the state of economics education.
Paul Krugman on Ireland
New York Times 23 Sept 2011
Look, standard Keynesian models, open-economy version, tell a very clear story about what happens when a country pegs its exchange rate at a level that leaves its industry uncompetitive.
The country doesn’t stay depressed forever: high unemployment leads to actual or at least relative deflation, which gradually improves cost-competitiveness, which leads to rising net exports and gradual expansion. In the long run, full employment is restored; it’s just that in the long run we’re all, well, you get the picture.
That was Keynes’s whole point in The Economic Consequences of Mr. Churchill — not that the return to gold at too high a parity would mean depression forever, but that it would subject Britain to years of unnecessary suffering.
Seeing some growth in Ireland, then, is not at all a refutation of Keynesian economics — it’s exactly what you’d expect, given that Ireland is in fact gradually achieving an “internal devaluation” via relative deflation.
Despite Keynes'protestations, the Chancellor of the Exchequer, Winston Churchill, announced on 28 April 1925 that Britain was returning to the pound at its prewar gold value (Skidelsky 1992: 200).
Churchill himself had expressed deep fears about the
wisdom of his policy, recognizing that it would create great hardship (Gilbert
1977: 97-8). In the middle of July, Keynes responded with a scathing set of
articles entitled "The Economic Consequences of Mr Churchill" (Keynes 1925).
He warned:
Mr. Churchill's policy of improving the exchange by 10 percent was, sooner or
later, a policy of reducing everyone's wages .... Deflation does not reduce
wages automatically. It reduces them by causing unemployment.
The proper
object of dear money is to check in incipient boom.
Woe to those whose faith
leads them to use it to aggravate a depression. (Keynes 1925: 208 and 220).
Jenkins skriver härom:
The momentum of conventional wisdom swept them (Keynes-McKenna)away...
a remarkable example of a strong not a weak minister nonetheless reluctantly succumbing,
grudgingly adjustning himself to the near unanimous, near irresistible flow of
establishment opinion.
Read more here
Germany’s incoming “grand coalition” of Christian Democrats and Social Democrats is about to commit the biggest economic policy error since unification – the attempt to pursue budget consolidation at the expense of all other economic policy goals. In doing so, it risks turning a five-year-long stagnation into a full-scale depression.
It would be more accurate, perhaps, to compare her /Ms Merkel/ to Heinrich Brüning, a Christian conservative who was German chancellor from 1930 to 1932.
Wolfgang Munchau, Financial Times, 7/11 2005
Wolfgang Munchau is an associate editor of the Financial Times
Är det rätt att stimulera ekonomin med ökade statliga utgifter i samband med en kris, som Keynes menade?
Eller kan stimulanspolitik snarare hämma den långsiktiga tillväxten, enligt Hayeks synsätt?
Om stimulansåtgärder finansieras med hjälp av tidigare överskott snarare än genom massiv belåning är riskerna med stimulanspolitik små.
Johnny Munkhammar och Nima Sanandaji, Svensk Tidskrift, 20 maj 2011
---
Grekland, Spanien och grunderna i macro
BNP är C + I + G +/- X Skall det vara så svårt att förstå för microhjärnorna?
Rolf Englund blog 2010-05-29
The debate over post-crisis monetary and fiscal policy has been heating up, on both sides of the Atlantic.
So who is right? It will come as no surprise that economists disagree deeply.
Martin Wolf, Financial Times, 2 June 2011
Mr Congdon notes, correctly, that reductions in the cyclically-adjusted fiscal deficit have coincided with economic expansions.
But the fact that A coincides with B does not mean A causes B.
B might cause A. Or C and D might cause A and B.
---
Thomas J. Sargent and Christopher A. Sims of the U.S. won the 2011 Nobel Prize in Economics "for their empirical research on cause and effect in the macroeconomy," the Royal Swedish Academy of Sciences said Monday
Thomas J. Sargent and Christopher A. Sims of the U.S. won the 2011 Nobel Prize in Economics
Mr. Sargent is perhaps best known for his work in the early 1970s on "rational expectations theory,"
WSJ 10 October 2011
"rational expectations theory," argues that people base their behavior not just on government policies but also on what they expect those policies and their impacts to be in the future.
Mats Persson tillhör Nobelkommittén för Ekonomipriset, som utdelat priset till bl a Robert Lucas, vars teser om marknadens rationella förväntningar
har sjunkit i värde efter den finanskris som inte kunnat hända om marknaden haft rationella förväntningar.
Rolf Englund blog 28 sept 2011
The disappointing economic data on US activity in recent months has brought a key policy debate back into focus.
The Keynesian side of this debate has been well served, with frequent outstanding contributions from Paul Krugman, Brad DeLong and others.
But I have had more trouble finding serious economic contributions from the classical school, even though they seem to be gaining ground in political and policy circles on both sides of the Atlantic.
For that reason, I was particularly interested in the recent lecture on the US recession given by the University of Chicago’s Robert Lucas.
Lucas is universally recognised as an intellectual giant, and his lecture gives a neat synopsis of what the classical school currently thinks, straight from the horse’s mouth.
Gavin Davies FT blog 31 may 2011
Dagens globala finanskris har utlöst en kris för ämnet nationalekonomi.
Sökandet efter bättre ekonomisk analys pågår för fullt.
Lars Jonung kolumn DN 29/4 2010
In a guest article,
Robert Lucas rebuts criticisms that
the financial crisis represents a failure of economics
The Economist print, Aug 6th 2009
---
A strange thing has happened to policy discussion: on both sides of the Atlantic,
a consensus has emerged among movers and shakers that nothing can or should be done about jobs.
Paul Krugman 29 May 2011
John Kay provides an enlightening discussion of our awkwardness in thinking about contingent events that cannot be pressed into a probabilistic framework – Rumsfeldian “unknown unknowns”
(“Why we struggle to make sense of our roulette wheel world”, Comment, March 16).
John Maynard Keynes, the eminent early 20th-century theoretician of probability, encapsulated the concept brilliantly in an article he wrote on another subject, economics:
Top of pageBernanke Leaps into a Liquidity Trap
If consumers wish to reduce their debt, and companies do not have a desirable menu of potential investments, there is little benefit in reducing interest rates
John P. Hussman, Ph.D. www.hussmanfunds.com, at John Mauldin 5/11 2010
"There is the possibility ... that after the rate of interest has fallen to a certain level, liquidity preference is virtually absolute in the sense that almost everyone prefers cash to holding a debt at so low a rate of interest. In this event, the monetary authority would have lost effective control."
- John Maynard Keynes, The General Theory
One of the many controversies regarding Keynesian economic theory centers around the idea of a "liquidity trap." Apart from suggesting the potential risk, Keynes himself did not focus much of his analysis on the idea, so much of what passes for debate is based on the ideas of economists other than Keynes, particularly Keynes' contemporary John Hicks. In the Hicksian interpretation of the liquidity trap, monetary policy transmits its effect on the real economy by way of interest rates. In that view, the loss of monetary control occurs because, at some point, a further reduction of interest rates fails to stimulate additional demand for capital investment.
Keynes Paradox of Thrift
The reason that the current recovery is below par is that the economy is experiencing a massive paradox of thrift.
Michael E. Lewitt, at John Mauldin, 1/11 2010
The most extended discussion of the paradox of thrift occurs in Chapter 23 of The General Theory, which is actually part of a series of chapters contained in Book IV entitled “Short Notes Suggested by the General Theory.” The discussion of the paradox of thrift in this chapter is primarily devoted to a historical survey of the idea and is relatively disjointed. Keynes’ clearest description of the concept comes much earlier in The General Theory when he writes the following:
“The reconciliation of the identity between saving and investment with the apparent ‘free-will’ of the individual to save what he chooses irrespective of what he or others may be investing, essentially depends on saving being, like spending, a two-sided affair. For although the amount of his own saving is unlikely to have any significant influence on his own income, the reactions of the amount of his consumption on the incomes of others makes it impossible for all individuals simultaneously to save any given sums. Every such attempt to save more by reducing consumption will so affect incomes that the attempt necessarily defeats itself. It is, of course, just as impossible for the community as a whole to save less than the amount of current investment, since the attempt to do so will necessarily raise incomes to a level at which the sums which individuals choose to save add up to a figure exactly equal to the amount of investment.”
In order for the fallacy of thrift to slow economic growth, the capital that consumers and businesses are saving would normally have to be available to recirculate in the economy through loans or investments. This recirculation is precisely what is not happening today, or at least not nearly at the rate necessary to lift growth to a level that would create significant job growth. And this is the Keynesian lesson that fiscal and monetary policymakers appear to have forgotten as they have forged their post-crisis strategy – rather than indiscriminately easing monetary conditions, it is necessary to create an environment in which savings-conscious consumers and corporations are willing to allow their funds to recirculate.
The reason that the current recovery is below par is that the economy is experiencing a massive paradox of thrift. A combination of factors has led individual economic actors – both consumers and corporations – to believe that it is in their best individual interest to save rather to spend, to repay debt rather than borrow. The result has been an increase in the personal savings rate from slightly negative to approximately 6-7 percent, and a significant improvement in corporate balance sheets (corporations are now sitting on approximately $1 trillion of cash). This has improved the financial condition of these individual economic actors, but deprived the broader economy of consumption and investment spending.
...
Savings and investment, being different activities, carried on by different people, could not simply be presumed identical.
John Maynard Keynes
A 69-year-old plan for dealing with imbalances in currency unions
One weekend in September 1941, John Maynard Keynes sat down in his farmhouse in Tilton to consider
how the world’s currencies might be managed once the war was over.
Within a few days the prolific economist produced two papers.
These set out his thoughts on what lay behind the breakdown in the early 1930s of the gold standard, in which currencies were linked at fixed rates to the gold price and so to each other.
The Economist September 23rd 2010
As Robert Skidelsky argues in his biography of Keynes*, this also reflected the contrasting views in America and Britain of the collapse of the gold standard.
America associated its earlier prosperity with the standard’s stability and the Depression with the system’s breakdown.
Britain linked the misery of the 1920s to the gold straitjacket and its subsequent recovery to being freed from it.
The belief that more discipline for debtors is the cure for imbalances persists, though in Germany rather than America.
Now a deficit country, America thinks surplus countries should adjust too.
“John Maynard Keynes: Fighting for Britain 1937-1946” (Macmillan, 2000)
Top of pageMy new maxim, never to stand in the middle of a fight between Paul Krugman and Niall Ferguson
It says a lot about the talents of John Maynard Keynes – and just as much about the shortcomings of modern macroeconomics – that when the financial crisis struck, policymakers instinctively reached not for their fancy models, but for the Keynesian idea of fiscal stimulus
Tim Harford, FT July 20 2010
If stimulus were to be the solution, what would be the problem?
The problem would be that too many of us wanted to save money or pay off debts; that is, we wanted others to pay for our services but weren’t so keen on paying for theirs right now.
Simple arithmetic suggests this would leave slack in the economy.
Fiscal multipliers are certainly fun.
If the fiscal multiplier is 0.5, we’re getting government projects at half price: the government project draws half its resources away from private-sector activity, but the other half is just soaking up slack.
If the fiscal multiplier is 1.6, as President Barack Obama’s Council of Economic Advisers has estimated, we get a free government project and a larger private sector.
It was in this future paradise that Keynes famously imagined that the economics profession might be thought of as “humble, competent people, on a level with dentists”. We economists have a way to go yet.
Keynes Versus Hayek, 1932
It’s deeply tragic that we’re having to have this debate all over again,
as the world economy slides into deflation and stagnation
Paul Krugman July 9, 2010
Are these hardships necessary?
The trick of the British establishment is to turn discussion from “whether to” into “how to” questions. The media debate is on which government services to cut or on the balance between spending cuts and tax increases. Once the discussion has been channelled into these trenches the establishment has won.
The real argument, however, should be on whether we need unparalleled fiscal austerity or not.
Samuel Brittan, FT June 17 2010
Keynes och moral hazard
Min hypotes är att det finns en makroekonomisk moral hazard (ung trygghetsrisktagande) som innebär att själva föreställningen, att det finns en kraftfull stabiliseringspolitik att ta till om det skulle gå snett, kan leda till stora obalanser.
Danne Nordling 4 mars 2010
Även om deras slutsatser skiljer sig åt är både Hayeks och Keynes teorier födda ur rädsla.
De är inte utopiska, de utlovar inget framtida lyckorike. De säger bara att den som följer deras läror har en god chans att undvika social kollaps, anarki och diktatur.
DN-ledare 4 mars 2010 signerad Henrik Berggren
The parallel with what happened in 1931 is irresistible.
The current stampede to thrift shows that the re-conversion to Keynes in the wake of the financial collapse of 2008 was only skin-deep
We are about to embark on a momentous experiment to discover which of the two stories about the economy is true
Robert Skidelsky, FT June 16 2010
Lord Skidelsky is emeritus professor of political economy at the University of Warwick.
His latest book is Keynes: The Return of the Master
The implicit premise of the coming retrenchment is that market economies are always at, or rapidly return to, full employment. It follows that a stimulus, whether fiscal or monetary, cannot improve on the existing situation. All that increased government spending does is to withdraw money from the private sector; all that printing money does is to cause inflation.
These propositions are a re-run of the famous “Treasury view” of 1929.
By contrast, Keynes argued that demand can fall short of supply, and that when this happened, government vice turned into virtue. In a slump, governments should increase, not reduce, their deficits to make up for the deficit in private spending.
Any attempt by government to increase its saving (in other words, to balance its budget) would only worsen the slump. This was his “paradox of thrift”.
The current stampede to thrift shows that the re-conversion to Keynes in the wake of the financial collapse of 2008 was only skin-deep: the first story remains deeply lodged in the minds of economists and politicians.
The parallel with what happened in 1931 is irresistible. In February of that year, Philip Snowden, the Labour government’s chancellor of the exchequer, set up the May Committee to recommend cuts in public spending.
Conservative spokesmen often claim that fiscal consolidation causes economies to recover. If so, the effect of the outbreak of public frugality in 1931 was curiously roundabout. Cuts in salaries produceda “mutiny” of naval ratings at Invergordon, suggesting that the empire was crumbling. This was enough to force Britain off the gold standard. A combination of sterling depreciation and lower interest rates revived exports and started a housing boom. But there was never a complete recovery until the war. Such evidence for the success of the cuts is the stuff of castles in the sky.
---
So far, so good. But here is my question: what is your “plan B”?
I have been fascinated – if appalled – by the pre-Keynesian approach you and the prime minister have taken to the UK’s fiscal challenges.
What Keynes called “the Treasury view” – that fiscal policy has no effect on activity, even in a deep recession – is alive and well in Downing Street.
Martin Wolf, 10 June 10 2010
The crucial issue for Spain and its European neighbours is the credibility of its “stability plan”, which outlines sharp cuts in government spending, including a near-freeze on hiring civil servants, and aims to reduce the deficit from 11.4 per cent of gross domestic product last year to 3 per cent of GDP in 2013.
Mr Zapatero and his ministers, like their foreign peers, deserve some sympathy for their post-Keynesian hangover. At a meeting in London this month Mr Zapatero recalled that the same organisations and markets that had demanded massive fiscal stimulus to avert an economic depression were now complaining about the resulting fiscal deficits. “What a paradox. What a contradiction,” he said.
The bad news for Mr Zapatero and other deficit-burdened European prime ministers is that the markets, impersonal yet fickle, do not give a damn about paradoxes or who was to blame yesterday for a problem today.
http://www.nejtillemu.com/spanien.htm#Unfortunately
If new-classical and new-Keynesian economics are both wrong, where do we go from here?
For 30 years, macroeconomists have been of two stripes: new-classical and new-Keynesian.
Neither has anything interesting to say about the current crisis.
Roger E.A. Farmer FT January 28, 2010
Har centralbankernas inflationsmålspolitik bidragit till krisen?
Hur kommer det sig att Keynes återuppstått?
Klas Eklund December 27th, 2009
Ekonomiläroböckerna och finanskrisen
I min egen lärobok, som har kommit i elva upplagor, finns visserligen en del avsnitt
om bubblor och om irrationaliteten och kasten på t.ex valutamarknaderna.
Men de avsnitten måste byggas ut till nästa upplaga.
Likaså måste Keynes få en grundligare behandling - inte minst begreppet “likviditetsfälla” och
hur den påverkar penningpolitiken.
Klas Eklund blog 2/3 2009
- Most mainstream macroeconomic theoretical innovations since the 1970s
(the New Classical rational expectations revolution associated with such names as Robert E. Lucas Jr., Edward Prescott, Thomas Sargent, Robert Barro etc, and the New Keynesian theorizing of Michael Woodford and many others)
have turned out to be self-referential, inward-looking distractions at best.
Rolf Englund agreeing with Willem Buiter, blogging at Maverecon, 5/2 2009
CNN uppfinner det Kenyesianska hjulet på nytt
Saving more and cutting debt might sound like a good plan to deal with the recession.
But if everyone does that, it'll only make matters worse.
Chris Isidore, CNNMoney.com senior writer, February 12, 2009
Time to plan for post-Keynesian era
Mainstream Keynesian economics is facing its last hurrah. The global fiscal stimulus championed last year by the Obama administration is coming undone, repudiated by the same Group of 20 that endorsed it last year.
Jeffrey Sachs, FT June 7 2010
Now, against a backdrop of a widening sovereign debt crisis, we need to abandon short-term thinking in favour of the long-term investments needed for sustained recovery.
Certain counter-cyclical spending is vital on social grounds. But stimulus measures such as temporary tax cuts for households or car scrappage schemes were dispiriting wastes of scarce time and money. They reflected a hope that a temporary fiscal bridge would carry us back to consumption and housing-led growth – a dubious proposition since the old “normal” had been financially unsustainable.Now we face a world economy with weak aggregate demand in the US and Europe, bulging budget deficits, sovereign debt downgrading and consumers unwilling to borrow. Governments are fighting for market credibility via draconian cuts in spending.
This too is the wrong approach. We should avoid a simplistic austerity to follow the simplistic stimulus of last year.
...
Lost Decade, Here We Come
The deficit hawks have taken over the G20
Paul Krugman June 6, 2010
This is a glorious moment to be an economist
Now we call for trillion dollar stimulus plans on the basis of little more than citing John Maynard Keynes
Benn Steil, Financial Times, February 5 2009
Keynes offers us the best way to think about the financial crisis
Martin Wolf, Financial Times, December 23 2008
Highly recommended
Svenskt Näringsliv gör helt om, dock utan att göra en pudel
Nu behövs en aktiv statlig finanspolitik där regeringen släpper loss reformer och offentliga jobb för cirka 50 miljarder det närmaste året.
Svenskt Näringslivs verkställande direktör Urban Bäckström och chefsekonom Stefan Fölster, DN Debatt 16/11 2008
Skall Urban Bäckström och Svenskt Näringsliv tvingas göra en pudel?
Rolf Englund blog 2008-10-26
Keynes had no sure cure for slumps
The recent collapse of speculation on houses is a non-monetary phenomenon
Edmund Phelps, Financial Times, November 4 2008
PIMCO’s Investment Committee to a man (no women yet) believes that capitalism is the best and most effective economic system ever devised,
but it has a flaw: it is inherently unstable.
Bill Gross, October 2008
The current crisis reminds us that, in a free economy, the price of the greatly improved long-term performance that only free economies can provide is an ineradicable economic cycle.
As John Maynard Keynes pointed out in the 1930s, the cause of the cycle is alternating moods of optimism and pessimism, and
its motor is credit, which enables optimism to determine economic activity.
Nigel Lawson. Time Magazine, October. 01, 2008
Many today are complaining about Alan Greenspan’s monetary stewardship, which kept these three locomotives stoked:
“serial bubble-blower” is the most polite phrase that I have heard.
But would the world economy really be better off today under an alternative monetary policy that kept unemployment in America at an average rate of 7% rather than 5%?
Would it really be better off today if some $300 billion per year of US demand for the manufactures of Europe, Asia, and Latin America had simply gone missing?
Brad DeLong April 05, 2008
The world economy, as John Maynard Keynes put it 75 years ago, is developing magneto trouble. What it needs is a push – more aggregate demand. In the US, the weak dollar will be a powerful boost to net exports, and thus to aggregate demand.
But, from the perspective of the world as a whole, net exports are a zero-sum game.
So we will have to rely on other sources of aggregate demand.
Inspired by John Maynard Keynes's “General Theory”, many economists in the 1960s and early 1970s viewed government tax and spending decisions as the prime tool for smoothing the economic cycle.
That confidence was later shattered by stagflation and rising budget deficits. The modern consensus has been that monetary policy, administered by an independent central bank, makes a better first weapon against recession than the whims of politicians.
But now, after more than three decades in the wilderness, Keynesian-style fiscal policy seems to be staging a comeback.
The Economist print 14/2 2008
Who is right depends on the answer to two questions.
Do countries have more room to use counter-cyclical fiscal policy than they used to?
And what is the evidence that it works?
With stingier unemployment benefits and a lower federal tax take, America has fewer “automatic stabilisers” than other rich countries do. Since many American states are forced, by law, to run balanced budgets they cut spending or raise taxes in a downturn—the opposite of Keynesian pump-priming. Federal-stimulus packages, in part, counter those trends. With higher tax burdens and more generous jobless benefits, European countries get a bigger fiscal boost without any change in policy.
The issue here is not whether there is going to be a recession in the world or individual countries,
but what governments and central banks could do about it.
There are many problems about policies to maintain activity,
but lack of policy instruments is not one of them.
Samuel Brittan, January 17 2008
Of course, things would be much easier if national authorities had used the recent expansion to strengthen their underlying positions, notably to put their budgets in order and at least to keep a weather eye on the growth of money and credit.
US three-month market interest rates at near 4 per cent still leave plenty of room for further reductions, as do euro rates. UK rates, at well over 5½ per cent, leave even more room. By contrast, during the last deflation scare, when Federal Reserve member Ben Bernanke alarmed financial coelacanths by talking (hypothetically) of helicopter money, US rates were down to just over 1 per cent.
RE: See also helicopters
Contrary to some alarmist fears, long-term rates did not move in the opposite direction, although they did not fall very much.
RE: See also Conundrum
If there really were to be a generalised lack of spending, national and international authorities would have the means to counteract it. There is no need to talk ourselves into a Great Depression.
RE: See Doom and 1929
Let's look at what Bernanke really said.
"Sustained deflation can be highly destructive to a modern economy and should be strongly resisted. Fortunately, for the foreseeable future, the chances of a serious deflation in the United States appear remote indeed, in large part because of our economy's underlying strengths but also because of the determination of the Federal Reserve and other U.S. policymakers to act..."
John Mauldin, 28/10 2005
Very Important Article
Classical economic theory suggests that interest rates automatically bring saving and investment into a productive balance.
The central principle of Keynesianism, however, is that this alignment between saving and investment is not always automatic, and that a misalignment can have serious consequences.
The Economist, Survey The World Economy, 22/9 2005
The modern consensus is that both classical and Keynesian theory can be right, but over different time frames. In the long term, saving and investment will be brought into line by the cost of capital. But in the short term, firms' appetite to invest is volatile, and policymakers may need to step in to shore up demand.
Thus, although saving and investment are equal ex-post, economic theory leaves plenty of room for an ex-ante saving glut.
It is little wonder that Mr Greenspan has become an almost legendary figure. Yet how good has his performance been and what lessons does his tenure bequeath?
Mr Volcker had to crush inflation. Mr Greenspan had merely to keep the show on the road.
Another reason for questioning the unique sagacity of the chairman is that low inflation has broken out all over the world.
Surprisingly for a man once known as a gold bug and disciple of Ayn Rand’s libertarian philosophy, Mr Greenspan has emerged as the policymaker closest in spirit to Maynard Keynes.
Martin Wolf, Financial Times, 19/10 2005
The burden of supporting the world economy can hardly rest indefinitely on the shoulders of Anglo-American shoppers and home owners.
Samuel Brittan 11/5 2007
Historical experience argues that monetary policy should be the first line of defence against both slump and inflationary boom.
Unfortunately, we cannot just leave matters here. It is easy to envisage situations in which both monetary and fiscal policy would be necessary to achieve a modicum of stability
Samuel Brittan, Financial Times 2/9 2005
Historical experience argues that monetary policy should be the first line of defence against both slump and inflationary boom. Not only can it be changed much more quickly and with less political embarrassment but the record suggests that fiscal changes on their own without adequate monetary backing are often ineffective. Moreover, monetary policy has the great virtue, when used as a stimulus, of not leaving behind a mass of deadweight debt to be serviced from the public purse.
Unfortunately, we cannot just leave matters here. It is easy to envisage situations in which both monetary and fiscal policy would be necessary to achieve a modicum of stability, but they would have to work together to do so
The not-so-golden rule, championed by Gordon Brown, the British chancellor of the exchequer, is to aim for a current balance but exclude public investment – now rising towards 3 per cent of GDP – from the calculation. This is, however, based on a false analogy with private investment. It would be much better, in my view, to accept a modest permissible overall deficit and put much less emphasis on the current-capital distinction.
None of these problems justifies the orthodox attitude, which is a form of “not in front of the children”. Many in the financial world know that unbalanced budgets may sometimes be theoretically desirable but are against admitting it, lest politicians misuse the knowledge and borrow to excess. This is the old fallacy of telling noble lies to encourage good behaviour. It is a good rule of thumb to avoid large budget deficits but it is not a principle to be pursued in all circumstances and at all costs.
Jag har sagt det förut. Persson har rätt i att det blir knepigt för Alliansen att gå till val på löfte om fler nya jobb tack vare sänkta ersättningsnivåer i socialförsäkringen.
Maria Abrahamsson, SvD-ledarsida 16/2 2006
Särskilt om detta sker i ett läge då den svenska ekonomin tuffar på bättre än på länge. För att vinna den matchen måste Alliansen bli klart bättre på att förklara sambandet mellan lägre ersättning och nya jobb.
I ett år nu har moderatkansliet försörjt politiska reportrar och kommentatorer med en ström av promemorior. De har utgått från förhållandet att ungefär en miljon svenskar i arbetsför ålder inte försörjer sig på arbetsmarknaden.
Utgångspunkten är alltså att det finns en mängd obesatta platser och att en rad människor är sjukskrivna trots att de kan arbeta. Till en del är detta naturligtvis sant, men bara till en del.
DN-ledare 28/9 2005
Arbetslösa ska söka jobb, sjuka ska söka doktorn, gör de inte det får de inga pengar. Så kan programmet sammanfattas i stark förenkling.
Utgångspunkten är alltså att det finns en mängd obesatta platser och att en rad männi-skor är sjukskrivna trots att de kan arbeta.
Till en del är detta naturligtvis sant, men bara till en del.
Det måste bli lättare både att anställa och avskeda, då får vi en rörligare arbetsmarknad. Och en rörligare arbetsmarknad erbjuder fler arbetstillfällen
Kommentar av Rolf Englund:
DN undviker huvudproblemet, att det finns för få lediga platser.
Det är lättare att avskeda i Sverige än i Tyskland, Frankrike och Spanien.
Arbetsbrist är saklig grund för avsked. Företagen anställer när det
finns arbete som behöver utföras som man inte klarar med den
befintliga arbetsstyrkan. Den totala efterfrågan är för låg.
Sänka ersättningsnivåerna för att få sjukskrivna och arbetslösa att
gå till arbetsförmedlingen skall man göra när det är brist på
arbetskraft och företagen inte får nog med arbetssökande. Det är
faktiskt inte läget i dag. Vet man inte det inom Alliansen?
Jag ställde frågan hur Lars Calmfors kunde tänka sig att den strukturella arbetslösheten skulle minska
genom att öka utbudet av arbetskraft.
Danne Nordling 22/9 2005
Min slutsats av detta är att DN-intervjun gav en missvisande bild av vad Calmfors egentligen tyckte. Detta återfaller på Johan Schück, som kanske inte fann det "lämpligt" att ställa frågor om stimulanspolitik som går stick i stäv med Alliansens solidariserande med en järnhård finanspolitik baserad på gamle Say.
The new German government’s deflationary macroeconomic policies will sabotage potentially favourable results of supply-side reforms.
The need for mutual support between pro-competitive supply-side reforms and expansionary macroeconomic policies should be obvious to anyone with an understanding of Keynesian economics.
It has been amply demonstrated in practice — positively by the success of the US and UK economies since the mid-1980s and negatively by the consistent forecasting failures of the pre-Keynesian economic flat-earthers of the European Central Bank
Anatole Kaletsky, The Times, September 19, 2005
Den svenska massarbetslösheten fordrar ett omfattande reformprogram som bygger om socialförsäkringarna, sänker skatterna på arbetsinkomster, uppmuntrar företagande och ökar flexibiliteten på arbetsmarknaden.
DN-ledare 19/9 2005
Ekonomin är för stel för att skapa ordentligt med nya jobb när det går uppåt, och i stället för att mjuka upp strukturerna vill regeringen mjuka upp statsfinanserna.
SvD-ledare 2005
Statens minus för 2006 uppskattades till 30 miljarder kronor - och det under ett rätt gynnsamt år, då man borde ha överskott och samla i ladorna.
The contrast between the macroeconomic management of the US and that of the eurozone during the past five years could not be greater
Where does this difference come from?
The practical men in Frankfurt have become the slaves of a theory telling us that the sources of economic cycles are shocks in technology (productivity shocks) and changes in preferences.
Paul de Grauwe, Financial Times 17/8 2005
The increasing attention paid to growing U.S. current account deficits has bred nightmare scenarios of a sharp decline in the foreign-exchange value of the dollar and rising U.S. interest rates.
Financial markets, by contrast, appear more sanguine. Inflation-indexed bonds in the U.S. are yielding only about 1.5% in real terms, and the IMF's estimate of the long-term world real interest rate is about 2%.
Glenn Hubbard, dean of Columbia Business School, was chairman of the Council of Economic Advisers under President George W. Bush,
Wall Street Journal, 23/6 2005
Vägen ur krisen gick via tuffa reformer. Budgeten sanerades, inflationen togs ned och den ekonomisk-politiska ramen blev trovärdigt stabil. Sysselsättningen i offentlig sektor reducerades och ersättningsnivåerna sänktes.
Men det har varken vänster eller höger kunnat erkänna. Vänstern har inte velat anklagas för högerpolitik, och högern har velat kritisera.
SvD-ledare 25/1 2006
Makroperspektivet till trots är rapporten läsvärd och innehållsrik. Här bara två reflexioner:
Författarna betonar att vägen ur krisen gick via tuffa reformer. Budgeten sanerades, inflationen togs ned och den ekonomisk-politiska ramen blev trovärdigt stabil. Sysselsättningen i offentlig sektor reducerades och ersättningsnivåerna sänktes. En rad marknader avreglerades, pensionssystemet moderniserades och lönebildningen fick större lokala inslag.
Man kan gräla om det rätta namnet på politiken, men den innebär att det blivit mindre av kollektivism och detaljstyrning. Men det har varken vänster eller höger kunnat erkänna.
Vänstern har inte velat anklagas för högerpolitik, och högern har velat kritisera.
Göran Persson: Människors uppoffringar har givit resultat
i regeringsförklaringen i Riksdagen, Tisdagen den 14 september 1999
Att reformera välfärdsstaten (SNS Förlag, 2006)
Sedan en tid har det hävdats att Sveriges sysselsättningsproblem både beror på och skulle kunna lösas med finans- och penningpolitiska stimulanser.
Keynes är ett passerat kapitel och så bör det förbli.
SvD-ledare 29/7 2005
Sedan en tid har det hävdats att Sveriges sysselsättningsproblem både beror på och skulle kunna lösas med finans- och penningpolitiska stimulanser. Att konjunkturen nu är stabil och svagt ökande samtidigt som sysselsättningen fortsätter att minska indikerar att även den debatten är en återvändsgränd. Keynes är ett passerat kapitel och så bör det förbli.
Kommentar av Rolf Englund:
Detta är en extrem ståndpunkt, snarlik den som Svenskt Näringsliv gav
uttryck för under EMU-omröstningen, när PJ Anders Linder var
deras informationschef.
Svenskt Näringsliv skrev då i sitt remissyttrande över SOU 2002:16, Stabiliseringspolitik i valutaunionen, slutbetänkande samt underlagsrapporter
Svenskt SOU 2002:16, Stabiliseringspolitik i valutaunionen (Buffertfonder):
Svenskt Näringsliv avstyrker det föreslagna finanspolitiska rådet.
Det finns inget behov för ett sådant eftersom vi anser att aktiv stabiliseringspolitik inte skall bedrivas.
Moderaterna vill se en utbudsexplosion på arbetsmarknaden genom stramare bidrag och lägre skatt på jobbinkomster.
Men partiet har få skarpa förslag som är inriktade på att öka den efterfrågan i ekonomin, som skulle möta det större utbudet.
Peter Wolodarski, DN 6/7 2005
Hur ska Sverige få fler arbetsgivare som är beredda att anställa? Den avgörande frågan saknar fortfarande Fredrik Reinfeldt ett bra svar på
De två inbjudna kommentatorerna, professor Assar Lindbeck och TCO:s Lena Hagman, var båda kritiska till moderaternas ensidiga fokusering på socialförsäkringarnas ersättningsnivåer.
Pengarna från besparingarna använder moderaterna till förvärvsavdrag som är relativt sett mest betydelsefulla för låg- och medelinkomsttagare. Det är en operation som ytterligare ökar skillnaden mellan att arbeta och lyfta bidrag.
Någon förändring av efterfrågan och den totala jobbmängden blir det knappast. Möjligen kommer de redan sysselsatta att spara en del av skattesänkningen till skillnad mot bidragstagarna. Det kommer att minska efterfrågan något och sålunda öka arbetslösheten.
Dessvärre har vi inte fått någon ytterligare information om hur det skulle gå till när kanske 300 000 jobb skulle skapas med moderaternas politik.
Danne Nordling, blog 5/7 2005
Strange things are happening in the world economy: falling interest rates on long-term securities, declining spreads between returns on safe and riskier assets, large fiscal deficits and huge global current account “imbalances” should not, in normal circumstances, coincide. So what is going on?
The answer, in a nutshell, is a global excess of desired savings against the background of weak investment, low inflation and ever more integrated economies.
To understand the present we need to go back to the 1930s. The “paradox of thrift” was the most counterintuitive and, to the classically trained economist, morally, theoretically and practically objectionable idea in John Maynard Keynes’ General Theory of Employment, Interest and Money, published in 1936, in response to the Great Depression.
Martin Wolf Financial Times June 13 2005
This year's Nobel prize honours two economists
Edward Prescott, of Arizona State University, and a Norwegian, Finn Kydland, of Carnegie Mellon University, honours research that has helped improve the practice of economic policy, as well as economists' understanding of booms and busts.
The Economist 14/10 2004
The two professors' work is based on a reconsideration of some of the ideas of John Maynard Keynes, an English economist whose theories held sway in the two or three decades after the second world war. His “General Theory of Employment, Interest and Money” laid out themes that were heavily informed by the Great Depression of the 1930s.
One was that economic recessions are caused in large part by a lack of “aggregate demand”, thanks perhaps to infectious bouts of mass pessimism.
While Keynesians were influenced by the hard times of the 1930s, this year's winners were inspired by the economic problems of the 1970s. Two features marked that decade.
First, there was “stagflation”, a combination of slow growth (or outright contraction) and high inflation. That perplexed many Keynesians, who thought that inflation came mostly with rapid growth.
The 1970s also saw a new desire among economists to understand an economy as the sum of millions of decisions by consumers and businesses, based ultimately on tastes and technological constraints; Keynes and his followers had tended to view the economy in aggregate terms, as if from a mountain top.
In a paper in 1977, they demonstrated the importance of credibility in economic policy. If governments cannot commit themselves credibly to a course, their policies may be futile.
Mr Kydland's and Mr Prescott's second Nobel-worthy idea, a new theory to explain business cycles, is more squarely opposed to Keynesian thought.
Rather than chalking up booms and busts to the vagaries of demand, as Keynes had done, they asked whether changes in technology, or other supply shocks such as a rise in oil prices, might be as important. After all, the American economy had grown sevenfold in the previous 100 years, thanks largely to improvements in technology. Might lulls in innovation be a prime cause of recessions, and surges a source of booms?
The professors found in one model that such fluctuations in technological growth could account for 70% of the swings of American business cycles in the post-war years.
This theory of “real business cycles” remains controversial. Many economists doubt that a depression like that of the 1930s could be explained mostly by variations in the pace of innovation.
“Real business cycles Home Page”
Nobelpristagare ekonomi 2004
Finn K. Kydland
Edward C. Prescott
Many economists find the real-business cycle theory totally unbelievable. No one can observe the technological shocks that are at the heart of this explanation, and it strikes many as simply ridiculous to argue that the unemployment during a recession is voluntary. On the other hand, the economists who have formed these arguments are among the brightest of the profession, and they can show that the patterns that their mathematical models generate are remarkably similar to the patterns that the real world generates.
Click here
Real business cycle theory to some extent went underground during the "years of high theory." Both Hayek and Keynes, while they drew from Wicksell, diverted our attentions away from traditional real business cycle theory mechanisms. Hayek blamed monetary expansion, while Keynes focused more on issues of animal spirits and liquidity premia, and sometimes sticky prices.
Click here
Satyajit Chatterjee, Senior Economist and Research Advisor, Federal Reserve Bank of Philadelphia
In an article published in 1986, Edward Prescott forcefully argued that during the post-World War II period, business cycles in the United States mostly resulted from random changes in the growth rate of business-sector productivity.1 He showed that upswings in economic activity occurred when productivity grew at an above-average rate and downswings occurred when productivity grew at a below-average rate.
Click here
Nouriel Roubini's Global Macroeconomic and Financial Policy Site
I Ekonomisk Debatt nr 7 2003 argumenterar Anders Borg för att
finanspolitiken bör ges en tydligare institutionell ram. Han
förundras också över svenska ekonomers keynesfobi
Martin Flodén,
Ekonomisk Debatt nr 1/2004
Fisher, Keynes, Minsky, and Keen on "Bubbles in Everything" and Debt Deflation
iTulip
Are We All Keynesians (Again)?
Our late Levy
Institute colleague Hyman Minsky has been vindicated once more
Policy
Note 2001/10
Indeed, the budget surpluses of the past three years, which have resulted from the long-term structural imbalance, are largely responsible for this downturn. Until a fundamental restructuring of the federal budget stance occurs, recovery is highly unlikely. What is needed is not a short-term fiscal stimulus, but a "permanent" relaxation of the fiscal stance. At a minimum, the cyclically adjusted fiscal relaxation that is required should reach the level of roughly $600 billion per year within the next several years.
Minsky, Hyman Stabilizing an Unstable Economy. New Haven, Conn.: Yale University Press.
Are Financial Markets Inherently Unstable?
Ten years on and sterling's
ejection from the European exchange rate mechanism
on Black Wednesday still
has a surreal quality about it.
Financial Times
2002-09-13
Picture the scene on September 16 1992. John Major's
senior ministers huddled around a borrowed transistor radio as the hurricane on
the currency markets washed away the government's economic policy and its
political authority.
The Bank of England's Eddie George pacing the prime
minister's temporary offices in Whitehall's Admiralty House, glued to his
pocket Reuters monitor as the Bank emptied it s foreign exchange reserves.
Interest rates raised to a breathtaking 15 per cent.
An ashen-faced
Norman Lamont, bathed
in television lights outside the Treasury, announcing, preposterously, that the
government had chosen to suspend sterling from the ERM.
A floating pound has rarely proved the shock absorber described by disciples of perfect markets. Nor has a fixed currency been the reliable lever of change imagined by those who want to force adjustments in the real economy.
Winston Churchill took the latter view when sterling was returned to the Gold Standard in 1925. Sane economics fell victim to sterling's totemic status. Churchill had his doubts about restoring the pound's convertibility to gold at $4.86, but he swallowed the argument that Britain could not own up to its waning economic power by choosing a lower rate.
The decision, denounced by John Maynard Keynes in his famous tract The Economic Consequences of Mr Churchill, helped tip Britain into the depression. .....more
Exchange Rates Precedents to EMU
In Discussion Paper No.
1390
Research Associate Tamim Bayoumi and Michael Bordo focus on two cases in which major countries returned to a fixed gold standard at previous parities: the resumption of specie convertibility by the US in 1879, and of gold convertibility by the UK in 1925.
These historical perspectives, they argue, may be of value in understanding issues involved when joining a fixed exchange rate regime particularly in the context of EMU and ERM. Bayoumi and Bordo compare the two experiences in order to examine the degree to which their success or failure reflects the exchange rate strategies themselves or the external environment in which the parity resumptions occurred.
A common set of macroeconomic fundamentals is examined so as to identify the important similarities and differences in underlying behaviour.
"What has Happened to
Monetarism?
An Investigation into the Keynesian Roots of Milton
Friedman's Monetary Thought and Its Apparent Monetarist Legacies"
Jörg
Bibow, The Levy Economics Institute, June 2002
Inflation can be too low
By Samuel
Brittan
Financial Times, June 5 2002 20:42
Bo Lundgren är av annan
mening
Är den
keynesianska ekonomin död?
Asienkrisen, Ryssland, IMF och
Argentina
Joseph Stiglitz
DN, 12 maj 2002
Remember fiscal policy?
How to use fiscal policy in a recession
The Economist Jan 17th 2002
Skyll Japankrisen
på Keynes
Mattias Lundbäck SvD ledarsida 2002-01-11
Divided we stand, united we fall
The
market requires individuals to act in their own self-interest.
But their
decisions can add up to recession
Michael Prowse, Financial Times; Nov 10,
2001
Keynes revisited
Gerard Baker and Ed Crooks,
Financial Times, October 5 2001 19:47
This week, with little ceremony, President George W. Bush quietly brought to a close more than a decade of US economic policy orthodoxy. By signalling his support for lower taxes and higher public spending in the next year that could reach as high as $130bn (£88bn) - 1.3 per cent of gross domestic product - he threw the US administration's weight behind the proposition that a temporary deficiency in aggregate demand should be met by a shift in government finances from surplus to deficit.
This argument, the simplest distillation of the teachings of John Maynard Keynes, has been out of favour in much of the industrialised world for 10 years or more. But with the world's three largest economies - the US, Japan and Germany - all in recession or close to it, the conventional wisdom is up for re-assessment.
At Saturday's gathering in Washington of finance ministers and central bankers from the Group of Seven leading industrial nations, the burden of expectation will fall on governments to play their part in averting global recession by cutting taxes and boosting public spending.
But as the US economy heads into recession, despite the sharpest reduction in the cost of short-term borrowing for a generation, fears are growing that the faith placed in monetary policy through the 1990s may be misplaced. Even some Federal Reserve policymakers are not so sure these days that interest rates alone can suffice. Fiscal policy is back in fashion.
The rest of the world, however, sees it rather differently. In Europe, as in the US, the 1990s was a decade of remarkable fiscal consolidation, driven in part by the requirements of the Maastricht treaty for countries that hoped to join the euro. The difference is that the Europeans generally still believe in trying to go further, at least over the long term. Although economic slowdown will inevitably mean that budget deficits are going to rise across the European Union, there is little enthusiasm for adding to those deficits with additional tax cuts or increases in spending.
When Gerhard Schroder, Germany's chancellor, talked about the need for a stimulus package for the EU this week, he was careful to stress that it would have to be delivered within the limits of the eurozone's stability and growth pact, which sets limits on budget deficits.
A Flawed Stimulus Plan
New York Times,
October 6, 2001
Responding to the demands of Republicans in Congress, President Bush has laid out a stimulus package that relies in large part on ineffective, irresponsible and regressive tax cuts.
http://www.nytimes.com/2001/10/06/opinion/06SAT3.html
Stimulate With Care
By Robert J. Samuelson
Thursday, October 4, 2001
Before the attacks, business investment and exports were declining while growth in consumer spending and housing was weakening. The economy was at a standstill -- or in recession. Prospects are now worse. In late September initial weekly unemployment claims hit 450,000, the highest since 1992. If the government doesn't give the economy a shove, it's not clear what will.
But what's justified in principle could be botched in practice. As Alan Greenspan warns, it is better "to be right than quick." The danger is that a stimulus package might become (along with anything labeled "anti-terrorism") a vehicle for all sorts of dubious tax giveaways or pork-barrel-spending increases. Three guidelines suggest themselves: (a) any stimulus program should be simple and noncontroversial, something the White House and Congress could enact quickly; (b) because the need for "stimulus" is temporary, it should not result in new permanent cuts in taxes or increases in spending; and (c) it should be effective in supporting the economy.
http://www.washingtonpost.com/wp-dyn/articles/A2679-2001Oct3.html
Stimulate With Care
By Robert J. Samuelson
Thursday, October
4, 2001
Before the attacks, business investment and exports were declining while growth in consumer spending and housing was weakening. The economy was at a standstill -- or in recession. Prospects are now worse. In late September initial weekly unemployment claims hit 450,000, the highest since 1992. If the government doesn't give the economy a shove, it's not clear what will.
But what's justified in principle could be botched in practice. As Alan Greenspan warns, it is better "to be right than quick." The danger is that a stimulus package might become (along with anything labeled "anti-terrorism") a vehicle for all sorts of dubious tax giveaways or pork-barrel-spending increases. Three guidelines suggest themselves: (a) any stimulus program should be simple and noncontroversial, something the White House and Congress could enact quickly; (b) because the need for "stimulus" is temporary, it should not result in new permanent cuts in taxes or increases in spending; and (c) it should be effective in supporting the economy.
http://www.washingtonpost.com/wp-dyn/articles/A2679-2001Oct3.html
That StimulatesWatching the debate over economic stimulus unfold on Capitol Hill, we keep remembering that the GOP has often been called the stupid party. So stupid, it seems, that it doesnt understand its own success.
Republicans emerged from a half-century as a minority party when Ronald Reagan discovered how to revive a troubled economy. He inherited inflation and stagnation, yet within two years sparked an amazing economic boom that still echoes today. The surging prosperity paved the way for Mr. Reagans Cold War victory and the rejuvenation of the American spirit. It also led to a GOP resurgence that culminated in control of Congress.
Alas, the Republicans seem to have forgotten their victory formula. Even in the Reagan years they never quite shook their accounting fixation on a balanced budget. They bought into an arbitrary concept of the deficitignoring the difference between capital and operating expensethat they would never apply to their own households. The Reagan program would have been even better without deficits, of course. But the plan was a historic success and the deficits (especially since much of it was defense spending) a price well worth paying.
Yet 20 years later we have Washington Republicans insisting not on the Reagan model, but preparing to give in to the model Democrats failed with in the 1970s.
At least Jimmy Carter proposed rebates for people who paid income taxes, though his plan was laughed out of town as trying to stimulate the economy by scattering dollar bills out of airplanes. Today the Democrats want rebates for people who dont pay any income taxes, and Republicans seem inclined to go along. While theyre at it, Republicans also cower when Democrats argue that any tax cut or increase must make the rich pay more, which means increasing marginal rates.
The pliant, dumb Republicans have forgotten that real stimulus means improving incentives for the most productive citizens. The Capitol Hill GOP is busy peddling tax cuts for business, only marginally better than Democratic handouts, because K Street lobbyists need something to justify their retainers to their corporate chiefs back in Stamford and Grosse Pointe.
http://interactive.wsj.com/articles/SB1002238129176007640.htm
Bush: Raising Keynes
By David Ignatius, Washington
Post, August 26, 2001
"We are all Keynesians now," the conservative economist Milton Friedman once famously remarked.
We were all Keynesians -- then Steve H. Hanke, Forbes Global, 02.22.99
You would think that the economic booms brought on by Margaret Thatcher and Ronald Reagan would have killed Keynesianism. They abandoned fiscal fine-tuning in favor of smaller government, less regulation and flatter taxes; for their efforts they got economic booms. And yet Keynesianism is not dead. It lives on in the moribund economy of Japan and the bankrupt policies the U.S. Treasury Department is foisting on that country. Like it or not, John Maynard Keynes will go down as one of the 20th century's most powerful economists. His 1936 classic, The General Theory of Employment, Interest and Money, popularized fiscal fine-tuning -- the notion that more government spending, less taxation or some combination of the two will cause an economy to accelerate by a multiple of the stimulus. And that a fiscal contraction will slow things down. A touch on the fiscal tiller is supposedly all that is needed to adjust demand so that it just matches an economy's capacity to produce. It was a neat theory, and it captivated two generations of economists, especially those who rather liked the idea of a strong central government. Even Richard Nixon, who claimed not to be a fan of big government, was moved to say, "We are all Keynesians now."
For proof that Keynes truly reigns supreme, all you had to do last week was watch President George W. Bush hawking his tax cut as a cure for the global economic slowdown. Bush made his remarks at a motorcycle plant -- hardly a Keynesian venue -- but the British economics sage himself couldn't have put the argument for fiscal stimulus any better.
What's more, my spies tell me that Alan Greenspan keeps a well-thumbed copy of Keynes's 1936 classic "The General Theory of Employment, Interest and Money" on his bookshelf at the Federal Reserve in Washington.
Keynes's weighty tome may not have quite the prominence in Greenspan's library of Ayn Rand's hymn to capitalism, "Atlas Shrugged." But the Fed chairman has been known to rise from his chair in mid-conversation and read aloud relevant passages from that 65-year-old book for visitors.
Handlingskraft: Nej tack
DN-ledare 2001-08-29
Kommer Göran Persson och Bosse Ringholm
att kunna hålla emot när vänsterpartiet och delar av
socialdemokratin ropar på gammaldags stimulanspaket?
När till
och med högerekonomer förespråkar keynesianism kan det vara
svårt.
Huvudproblemet är regeringens ovilja att
genomföra strukturella reformer
SvD-ledare
2001-08-30
Keynes återkomst
Ledare i Dagens Industri 2001-08-20
Keynes lives
By
Robert Skidelsky
Financial Times, August 15 2001 19:06GMT
Lord Skidelsky is professor of political economy at Warwick university.
The
third volume of his biography of John Maynard Keynes was published in November
A limited cure for
recession
Samuel Brittan, Financial Times, July 18 2001
Other People's Money
By PAUL KRUGMAN
New York Times, July 18,
2001
Rolf Englund on Keynes - Artiklar av Danne Nordling, utredningschef på Skattebetalarna
Handlingskraft: Nej tack DN-ledare 20010-82-9
ALLT FLER OROAS över den vikande konjunkturen. I medierna sprids bilden av en kris i vardande, och allt fler ropar på keynesiansk stimulans från politiker och riksbanker.
Den ansedda marknadsliberala ekonomitidskriften The Economist propagerar till och med för att stabilitetspakten i EU ska brytas upp, för att ge utrymme för en mer aktiv konjunkturpolitik med sänkta skatter och högre budgetunderskott.
Vad handlar då konjunkturpolitik om? Dels kan politikerna genom sänkta skatter och ökade bidrag försöka hålla uppe den privata konsumtionen. Dels kan riksbanker sänka räntan för att försöka frammana fler och större investeringar.
Problemet är att ingen vet om och hur sådana åtgärder fungerar.
Ekonomi, precis som all annan mänsklig verksamhet, kan inte detaljplaneras, styras eller förutses. Människor handlar utifrån känslor, privata irrationella motiv och gör helt enkelt sällan som prognosmakare eller politiker tänker sig. Om du får mera pengar i plånboken kanske du vill köpa en ny bil och därmed öka konsumtionen av kapitalvaror. Men du kanske ännu hellre betalar av några gamla lån, sparar pengarna till din planerade Australien-resa eller ställer till med en stor härlig födelsedagsfest för alla släktingar och vänner.
OM DE EUROPEISKA politikerna dessutom skulle överge den kloka politik som varit vägledande under hela 1990-talet, med låg inflation och sunda statsfinanser, skulle det få än mer svåröverskådliga konsekvenser.
Säg att ett land ökar sina underskott för att föra en expansiv politik. Då riskerar det att leda till högre inflation, och därmed till högre räntor, som i sin tur ger mindre pengar att röra sig med för alla privatpersoner med banklån. Resultatet blir mindre, inte mer, pengar över för vanliga människor.
Det politiker kan göra är att se till att det generellt är så goda villkor som möjligt för att arbeta och för att investera. Det är kanske inte lika kul som att lägga fram storstilade paket med mer pengar till väljarna, som kan leda till mer väljare för det aktuella partiet, men det bästa är faktiskt att inte lägga sig i konjunkturer för mycket. Blir det en akut kris, som i Sverige i början på 1990-talet, då krävs det extraordinära åtgärder. Men inte nu, i en förhållandevis mild konjunkturavmattning.
FÖR AVMATTNINGEN ÄR relativt mild, trots katastrofvarningarna från olika håll. Konsumtionstrycket är högt, arbetslösheten minskar fortfarande, inflationen, liksom räntan, är låg och människor känner sig ganska trygga i sin ekonomiska situation. Redan aviserade åtgärder som höjt barnbidrag och sänkt fastighets- och förmögenhetsskatt kommer också att göra att hushållen får en ökad disponibel inkomst framöver.
Den nuvarande situationen är en prövning för våra politiker. Kommer Göran Persson och Bosse Ringholm att kunna hålla emot när vänsterpartiet och delar av socialdemokratin ropar på gammaldags stimulanspaket? När till och med högerekonomer förespråkar keynesianism kan det vara svårt. Kommer budgetsanerar-mästaren Persson att tillåta högre underskott och än en gång sätta sig i skuld till finansmarknader världen över?
Att det är svårt och i grunden oklokt att försöka påverka konjunkturer betyder emellertid inte att det inte finns saker att göra. Sverige har fortfarande stora strukturella problem med höga skatter på arbete, krångliga företagsregler, inte minst för de så kallade fåmansföretagen som drivs av entreprenörer och orättvis förmögenhetsbeskattning. Det är bra att något nu ska göras åt skatten på boende, och det vore önskvärt om regeringen fortsatte med andra viktiga skattesänkningar.
PÅ SAMMA SÄTT finns strukturfel inom alltifrån skolan till socialförsäkringarna. Det finns alldeles för viktiga strukturförändringar att tänka på för att politikerna ska ägna sig på heltid åt fåfänga konjunkturanpassningar.
Huvudproblemet är regeringens ovilja
att genomföra strukturella reformer
SvD-ledare 2001-08-30
Chansen för en blygsam återhämtning framåt årsskiftet anses vara god, men dessa förhoppningar kan knappast läggas till grund för regeringens ekonomiska politik, oavsett hur välgrundade de må vara.
Huvudproblemet är regeringens ovilja att genomföra strukturella reformer som kan rädda landet från den utsatta rollen som den globala konjunkturens lekboll. En internationell nedgång påverkar alla, men de sämst rustade drabbas hårdast.
Visst kan vi hoppas och tro på en snar ekonomisk återhämtning, ledd av USA. Men - utöver det som president George W Bush bidrar med - är det hög tid för den svenska regeringen att stimulera det privata nyföretagandet.
Handlingskraft:
Nej tack
DN-ledare 2001-08-29
Kommer Göran Persson och Bosse
Ringholm att kunna hålla emot när vänsterpartiet och delar av
socialdemokratin ropar på gammaldags stimulanspaket?
När till
och med högerekonomer förespråkar keynesianism kan det vara
svårt.
Gamla hjältar till heders igen
Klas Eklund på SvD ledarsida
2001-08-24
Lärdomen? Konjunkturcykeln är inte död. Tvärtom gäller det för ekonomerna att återuppliva de gamla, halvt glömda konjunkturmodellerna från Hayeks och Keynes dagar och återgå till ritbordet.
"Against All Odds: How the Adam Smith Model of
Free-Market Capitalism Triumphed over Keynesiansim, Marxism and Socialism"
lecture att Timbro May 28 2001
Keynes är
stendöd
SvD-ledare 2001-03-22
The Keynesian genie is recalled
from the bottle
Gerard Baker, Financial Times, May 3, 2001
For years they have met in dwindling gatherings, offering mutual support and reassurance in an effort to keep the flame of their faith flickering in a hostile world.
Like persecuted religious sects in totalitarian countries, they have been subjected to biting ridicule for their adherence to a philosophy that is publicly derided by the establishment as primitive and outmoded. They have watched in despair as many of their former fellow-believers have abandoned them, publicly recanted, and joined the march along the safe and broad boulevards of conventional thought.
But suddenly, just as their creed looked set to be consigned to official historical textbooks on ideological error, the small band of believers who still subscribe to Keynesian thought are emerging from their captivity into the blinding daylight of public economic debate.
The Economist, 2000-11-23: This week sees the publication of the third and final volume of Robert Skidelskys biography of John Maynard Keynes, one of the greatest and most influential thinkers that Britain has ever produced. We asked Lord Skidelsky to tell us about his biographical adventure and, now that the labour is done, to say what he thinks of the man
Three insights helped to orient me. The first was Joseph Schumpeters distinction between an economists vision and his analytic scheme. Keynes applied this distinction to himself. The economist, he told his Cambridge students in 1933, always knows more than he can say. When you adopt perfectly precise language, he went on, you are trying to express yourself for the benefit of those who are incapable of thought. Keyness strictures were in vain. Since his day, economics has become so formal, or mathematicised, that even economists can no longer understand what they are saying to each other, still less the educated public. Keyness appeal as an economist has always been to those who prefer fertile thinking to elegant proofs.
Secondly, I was influenced by Axel Leijonhufvud. In his book On Keynesian Economics and the Economics of Keynes (1966), Leijonhufvud argued that a thinkers thought will show a consistency and continuity of development which, once grasped, make it possible to view his work as a coherent whole. This was very much to the point. There is an unmistakable family resemblance running from Keyness early paper, How Far Are Bankers Responsible for the Alternation of Crisis and Depression? (1913) through his Tract on Monetary Reform (1923) and his Treatise on Money (1931) to The General Theory of Employment, Interest and Money, which distinguishes them sharply from the orthodox economics being produced at the time.
I was also struck by Peter Clarkes demonstrationin his fine book, The Keynesian Revolution in the Making (1988)of just how close Keyness theoretical ears were to the political and administrative ground. There was much of the civil servant in Keynes. Theory must always be serviceable for policy, even if its echoes went beyond practical requirements.
The enduring legacy of Keynes
The great British economist deserves best to be remembered for his
doctrine of the macroeconomic risks of oversaving
Samuel Brittan, Financial
Times, November 23, 2000
A limited cure for recession
Samuel
Brittan, Financial Times, July 18 2001
Even the most pessimistic of analysts see some scope for official action to prevent a downturn from getting out of control. The one thing of which we can be sure about the present setback to the world economy is that nobody knows how long or deep it will be.
The epicentre of the present disturbance is the US economy. Stories of surprising consumer confidence are succeeded by reports of sagging business confidence. Even if there is some recovery in the second half of this year, we shall not know if it is a breathing space or the beginning of a durable recovery.
One disturbing sign is the reassuring statements that emerge from meetings of world finance ministers and central bankers. At the beginning of 2001 central bankers meeting at Basle proclaimed that a US recession was unlikely. Not long afterwards Alan Greenspan, chairman of the US Federal Reserve, warned of just this danger.
This month finance ministers of the summit group spoke about sound economic fundamentals that would provide a solid foundation for renewed expansion.
There is a certain amount of consensus that we are back with the pre-1914 kind of investment-led business cycle. But the nature of the traditional business cycle is still a matter of dispute.
We can distinguish two schools of thought. There are those who regard recessions as mainly reflecting a falling-off in demand for products or labour, which can be corrected by injecting more spending power.
There is also a more pessimistic school that sees in a recession a penalty for previous indulgences.
According to the demand-based school, recessions are due to whatever causes total spending to falter. Policies to increase spending can take the economy back towards its trend growth rate, although not above it.
This view is common to monetarists and Keynesians alike. These differ on the relative importance of monetary and fiscal policy, the difficulty of forecasting and rules versus discretion. But they basically agree that policies that maintain demand can cure recessions.
The more pessimistic school sees the origins of recession in the excesses of the previous boom. In its view, real and sustainable recovery will not be possible until the excesses have been corrected. There are different kinds of pessimists - the most respectable are the academic economists of Austrian vintage.
There is more than one kind of Austrian. To those who follow Joseph Schumpeter, the Viennese economist who settled in Harvard, the mainspring of economic growth is a series of bursts of innovation.
According to another variant, led by Ludwig Von Mises and Friedrich Hayek, the problem is that during the boom investment exceeds societys permanent willingness to save and is therefore distorted in an excessively capital-intensive direction. Full economic recovery has to wait until this mistaken investment has been corrected.
Hayek at least made one significant concession. While he insisted that the investment downturn would have to run its course, he did see a place for expansionary policies to prevent what he called a secondary depression.
This refers to a multiplier process in which a downturn in investment leads to reduced incomes, which in turn feeds into lower consumption and so on in a downward spiral.
Unfortunately, this concept was not formulated in time to save the theory from intellectual annihilation.
The relevant point is the agreement among these schools of thought that a cumulative process, in which consumption and income lead each other downwards, can be avoided.
It is helpful here to look at some orders of magnitude. Private non-residential investment, in which the past excesses are supposed to lie, has accounted in recent years for about 13 per cent of US gross domestic product.
The overwhelming proportion of GDP - 67 per cent - consists of personal consumption and the second largest category - 17.5 per cent - consists of government spending.
Therefore, even if the pessimists are right about the excesses of the preceding investment boom, it is at least possible to cushion a recession by boosting consumption and government spending.
With a Republican administration in Washington, the fiscal boost can be expected to take the form of tax cuts.
The practical question is: how far can we go in stimulating consumption - type spending to offset weaknesses in the investment component?
The question then boils down to how far central banks and governments can go in boosting consumer spending as a stabiliser.
But there is another, more controversial, kind of limit. Before the downturn began, the American consumer was tightly stretched in terms of high debt and low savings ratios. While no one wants to see a downward spiral in consumer spending, a deliberate large boost to make up for shortfalls in investment could take the US consumer spending ratio into vulnerable territory in terms of susceptibility to a future shock.
The US private sector is already running a historically high deficit that has been financed by overseas borrowing, in turn mirrored in a record current payments deficit.
Other People's Money
By PAUL
KRUGMAN
New York Times, July 18, 2001
It wasn't true when Richard Nixon said it, but it is true today: We are all Keynesians now at least when we look at our own economy. We give anti-Keynesian advice only to other countries.
When it comes to the U.S. economy, everyone including people who imagine that they have rejected Keynesianism in favor of some doctrine more congenial to the free-market faithful in practice views the current slowdown in terms of the intellectual framework John Maynard Keynes created 65 years ago.
In particular, everyone thinks that during a slump what we need is more spending.
Before Keynes, the general view was quite the opposite: economic slumps were supposed to be the invisible hand's way of punishing excesses, and the best cure was supposed to be a good dose of austerity, public and private. Only as a result of the Keynesian revolution did it become obvious to everyone so obvious that people take it for granted that the problem during a slump is too little spending, not too much, and that recovery depends on persuading the public to start spending again.
So every time you read an article worrying that declining consumer confidence may tip us into recession, or that interest rate cuts will soon spark a recovery, or even that this time interest rate reductions may not do the trick, you are reading Keynesian economics. Like the man who was unaware that he had been writing prose all his life, these writers may not know that they are Keynesians but they are.
And you would have to search far and wide to find anyone who thinks that the U.S. government should slash spending and raise taxes to offset the budget impact of this year's downturn, or who thinks that the Fed is wrong to cut interest rates in the face of a slump. (There are some people who think that the Fed has overdone it but they aren't opposed to the policy in principle.)
But we by which I mean both policy makers in Washington and bankers in New York often seem to prescribe for other countries the kind of root-canal economics that we would never tolerate here in the U.S.A.
En lärd men för de flesta begriplig artikel av Milton Friedman om John Maynard Keynes (pdf 212kb) kan downloadas från http://www.rich.frb.org/eq/spg97/friedman.pdf
Sylvia Nasar, Bloomberg 9 September 2011
In January 1919, as the Allied leaders met in Paris to hammer out a treaty ending World War I, famine and pestilence raged from St. Petersburg to Istanbul.
In the early morning hours of May 4, Keynes was pacing through Paris’s deserted streets, pondering an early draft of the Versailles treaty, when he ran into two friends, one of them Herbert Hoover, head of the Allied food relief program. “We all agreed it was terrible,” Hoover wrote in his memoir.
The incorrigible optimist retreated to bed, ill with the flu and depressed by his failure to persuade the Big Four to focus on economic recovery. Feeling like “an accomplice in all this wickedness and folly,” Keynes made up his mind to resign, he confided in a letter. “The Peace is outrageous and impossible and can bring nothing but misfortune.”
By Christmas, Keynes had exacted some measure of revenge on the Big Four -- including his boss, British Prime Minister Lloyd George -- by publishing a brilliant peroration, “The Economic Consequences of the Peace.”
It savaged the treaty, and was as memorable for its acid portraits of the men in charge as for its gloomy conclusions.
Keynes argued that the treaty had sown the seeds of another war by adding to the loser’s debts while wresting away their means of paying them.
Vengeance will not limp, he warned, “and nothing can then delay for very long that final civil war between the forces of reaction and the despairing convulsions of revolution.”
The Project Gutenberg eBook, The Economic Consequences of the Peace, by John Maynard Keynes
Click here
No country can be expected to generate huge primary surpluses for long periods for the benefit of foreign creditors.
Meeting debt burdens at rates currently charged by the official sector for credit – let alone the private sector – would involve burdens on Greece, Ireland and Portugal comparable to the reparations’ burdens Keynes warned about in The Economic Consequences of the Peace.
Lawrence Summers, Financial Times, 18 July 2011
Review
of John Maynard Keynes, The Economic Consequences of the Peace
by
Thorstein Veblen
The Economic Consequences of the Peace, by John Maynard Keynes, 1919
----
I today, April 11th 2011, hereby declare to have invented the phrase
The Economic Consequences of the Peak
Rolf Englund Read more here
-------
Would-Be Keyneses Fight Over Economic
Strategy,
September 25, 1998, Wall Street Journal
The Atlantic Monthly
Historic
article written by John Maynard Keynes in The Atlantic Monthly
during the Great Depression (May 1932), maintaining that the avoidance of
financial collapse represents the primary economic problem to be solved
in the United States, more than the restoration of industry. Keynes
doubts that the U.S. will be able to solve its own economic problems and
suggests that Great Britain may provide the financial leadership sought in
America and overseas.
The Science of Monetary
Policy: A New Keynesian Approach
Richard Clarida, Jordi Gali, Mark
Gertler
NBER Working Paper No. W7147 Issued in May 1999
Behöver vi en ny Keynes?
av Mats Ekelund, doktorand i
nationalekonomi vid Handelshögskolan i Stockholm, i Smedjan
I Asienkrisens spår har allt fler börjat tala om behovet av en ny Keynes. Men försöken att skaka liv i Keynes är dömda att misslyckas. Det som behövs är en ny Milton Friedman, som kan lyfta fram marknadsekonomins många positiva och välfärdsskapande mekanismer.
http://smedjan.com/smedjan/artiklar/9903/ekelund.asp
Göran Greider i DN 98-05-19 om Keynes
(Kommentar RE: I detta fall säger han vad jag själv tycker, t o m kanske bättre än vad jag själv kunnat formulera det.)
...När utopin är förverkligad år 2001 kommer antalet anställda inom offentlig sektor ändå att vara långt färre än för bara sju år sedan. Och saken är ju den att detta betraktas som en oerhört ambitiös målsättning. De sjunkande förväntningarnas förnöjsamhet har inträtt. Jag stirrar på de välkända siffrorna. De speglar ett mentalt skifte. Dagens framtidsförhoppningar är sämre än till och med gårdagens realiteter! Förväntningarna har brutits ned i svensk och europeisk politik.
Det keynesianska tänkesätt som i sextio år var närvarande hos världens politiker - från Wigforss till Nixon - är i dag utraderat ur tänkandet. När jag håller föredrag i landet kan en och annan rycka till när jag talar om Marx, han som ville störta kapitalismen. Men nämner jag Keynes - som ville rädda samma system - och insinuerar att besparingspolitiken under nittiotalet kanske var fel från början till slut, då reser sig en del från stolarna och vill lämna lokalen.
Många av dem som ändå upprest sig mot besparingarnas effekter kan heller inte riktigt tro på att det faktiskt, en gång i tiden, fanns ett brett samförstånd kring idén att det inte går att spara sig ur kriser. Gårdagens realiteter har blivit otroliga sagor för de nu levande. Ett intellektuellt arv har försetts med giftstämpel, och inte ens under de perioder under detta nittiotal när ren deflation - prisfall - rått i svensk ekonomi har stimulansåtgärder kunnat diskuteras utan att bemötas med närmast hån.
I Europa är det många som inte arbetar av Kurt Wickman
Europa har gått från full sysselsättning på
1970-talet till massarbetslöshet under 1990-talet trots en unikt
långvarig högkonjunktur däremellan.
Fil dr Kurt Wickman
analyserar i denna rapport orsakerna, som inte finns att söka vare sig i
för låg efterfrågan eller i de ekonomiskt-politiska
konvergenskraven.
Utan några paralleller i övrigt kan konstateras att krisen i den svenska välfärdsstaten har frammanat liknande reaktioner. Statsskulden, budgetunderskottet och de stora offentliga utgifterna, som av merparten av samhällsdebattörerna ses som allvarliga problem, anses i vissa kretsar inte vara några reella företeelser, utan produkter av en ideologiskt motiverad förtalskampanj mot välfärden driven av näringslivet och den politiska högern.
I föreliggande rapport ger fil doktor Kurt Wickman, författare till ett flertal böcker om svensk ekonomi, en bild av hur några av dessa konspirationsteoretiker resonerar. Wickman riktar i sin rapport bland annat skarp kritik mot de så kallade nykeynesianernas argumentation och sätt att handskas med fakta.
Patrik Engellau: Så här, ungefär, resonerar (fåtalet kvarlevande) keynesianer:
Lars Calmfors om svängningen från Keynes till det tappra kronförsvaret 1992 - ur DN november 1992